Splitting Deutsche Bank?

With a cumulative balance sheet nearly as big as the GDP of the EU-27 (94% as of 2015), the...

The EU’s role in international financial bodies

Who sets the rules governing the financial sector? What interests are represented? If we look at Europe, financial...

Hiding in Plain View: Why economists can’t see the obvious coming

The meteor that wiped out the dinosaurs 65 million years ago was not a “Black Swan”. It was...

Representation of public interest in banking #4 – The banks, the public and the secluded world of the BCBS: who has access?

Bank lobbying around this month’s meeting of the Basel Committee of Banking Supervision shows how far the pendulum...

Grand Theft Europe scandal – one more reason to #ChangeFinance

A constant shower of damning reports on opacity and scandals in the financial sector is the result of...

About the decisions taken by European bank regulators and supervisors in the face of the coronavirus crisis

Our analyses of the coronavirus crisis: Bank regulators and supervisors have taken a number of important measures over...

Caritas France joins the fight to re-regulate finance

Regulating finance is a necessity for all The power of financial markets in shaping our societies wouldn’t be...

The stage is being set for another financial crisis

2008: A Crisis We Should Have Learned From In 2008, the world experienced the worst financial crisis since...

Bottom-up approaches to corporate governance in the financial sector

Interest of beneficiaries in responsible investment Europeans continue to experience the impact of the financial crisis, including unemployment,...

The insufficient role of EDIS in restoring trust in banks

Banks are uniquely prone to runs because they borrow short and lend long, creating a maturity mismatch in...

Monitoring derivatives trading books in the current context of financial markets turmoil

OUR ANALYSES OF THE CORONAVIRUS CRISIS: Managing derivatives positions in a controlled manner requires that a number of...

The last stretch: reaping the benefits of the sustainable finance framework

In 2018, as part of the European Green Deal, the European Commission presented an EU action plan on sustainable...

Plus de dérégulation de la finance ne soutiendra pas les PME

S’exprimant lors des « Conférences citoyennes » à Epinal le 17 avril dernier, Emmanuel Macron a réitéré sa proposition de...

Finance Watch’s view on the COVID-19 Banking Package

OUR ANALYSES OF THE CORONAVIRUS CRISIS: The COVID-19 Banking Package: More flexibility in the EU’s banking rules On...

Деофшоризация в финансах: как регуляторы ужесточают контроль за низконалоговыми юрисдикциями

В последние годы глобальные регуляторы ведут активную борьбу с уходом компаний в офшоры, стремясь вернуть налогооблагаемые активы в...

New trade deals restrain governments on financial regulation

Ten years after the 2008 crisis, we are still not protected from new financial crises. Yet, the CETA...

Still Going Round in Circles: The Revolving Door Between Banks And Their Regulators

The European Banking Authority (EBA) is one of the most important organisations overseeing rules and setting technical standards...

Hypertrade Crypto: Democratizing Algorithmic Trading for the Digital Asset Era

The cryptocurrency market operates at a relentless pace, a 24/7 global arena where volatility is the only constant....

Financial regulation: Small victories on revolving doors

In an unprecedented move to avoid conflicts of interest, the European Parliament rejected the nomination of an ex-lobbyist,...

A Paradise for the 0.1%

We should not be surprised at the scale of tax evasion revealed by the Paradise Papers. As the name...

The insufficient role of EDIS in restoring trust in banks

Banks are uniquely prone to runs because they borrow short and lend long, creating a maturity mismatch in their balance sheets that is inherently unstable. This is, however, a necessary part of banks’ ability to provide liquidity to borrowers and depositors at the same time, one of the key economic functions of banks. Deposit insurance helps banks to sustain partially this maturity mismatch while reducing the chances of runs and contagion.

Deposit insurance also has a significant political appeal because it addresses citizen’s concerns about the safety of their deposits, especially in light of recent financial crises. On the other hand, it may exacerbate the very serious problem of moral hazard in banking.

Strengthening the EU’s financial system

Moral hazard became evident in the crisis when the implicit state backing of banks’ deposit-taking arms was made explicit through bail-outs. The safety net encouraged banks to develop highly leveraged and risky trades while being assured of public support in the event of a major loss. Banks had incentives to add risk because they could capture any profit but shift any losses to the state. The comforting assumption that banks would always be protected also reduced the incentives of investors first and depositors second to monitor banks properly.

For these reasons, governments have installed elaborate systems of banking regulation, supported by entry restrictions, activity restrictions, examinations, resolution regimes, commitments against bailout and sanctions. Deposit insurance adds to this system, especially if it is set up with risk reduction features, incentives for large depositors, investors and shareholders to monitor their banks (because of bail-in), and an institutional framework to allow enforcement of these safeguards.

The European Commission set up such an institutional framework in June 2012 with the Banking Union, whose aims include ending the “vicious circle” between banks and their sovereigns (when solvency problems at banks affect the solvency of the state and vice versa). So far, the Banking Union comprises two main pillars: the single supervisory mechanism (SSM) and the single resolution mechanism and fund (SRM/SRF). A third pillar, common deposit insurance, also announced as a key component in June 2012, proved controversial with some member states and so a political decision was taken to base it on “harmonized” rules at the national level, undermining efforts to weaken the “vicious circle”. These efforts were further undermined by the resolution regime, which leaves responsibility for dealing with failed banks partially at the national level, and the continued lack of a European fiscal backstop, which means national taxpayers are still the final backstop.

The proposal for a European Deposit Insurance Scheme (EDIS) is therefore seen as an incremental, but insufficient, component of a truly single European banking system and a natural complement to the single currency, since it would ensure, in theory, the same level of confidence in the safety of deposits irrespective of their location. Moreover, EDIS would align the control of European deposit protection with liability for it. As banking supervision and resolution were lifted to the European level, deposit protection should follow. A part of the logic of the Banking Union seems to be geographical: banks have grown too large for their sovereigns, in part because of their international operations and in part because of their trading operations; therefore the solution is to move resolution to the European level. As some of the changes to banks over the last 25 years have been caused by cross border expansion within the European Union and the Europeanization of the banking sector, there is some logic to this move.

A phased implementation of EDIS

The Commission’s proposal on EDIS looks reasonable, although the final outcome will be decided by the co-legislators: the Council and the European Parliament. The variety of political objectives among different member state suggests that negotiations will not be easy. Proposals on mutualisation and borrowing capacity were previously rejected by some member states while negotiating the deposit guarantee scheme directive of 2010. With EDIS, these become a focal point once again as EDIS aims to move responsibility to the European level in three stages. It starts with the re-insurance system based on the national deposit schemes, gradually moving to coinsurance, and ending with a fully mutualized EDIS by 2024.

In the first re-insurance stage, EDIS would only provide an additional source of funding to that of the national Deposit Guarantee Schemes (DGS), thereby making a limited contribution to ending the link between banks and their sovereigns. It is therefore desirable to aim for a progressive mutualisation from the co-insurance stage to the full insurance stage.

The reinsurance scheme as designed should pool risks and weaken sovereign-bank links. Ex ante agreement on the shares of national and supra-national funding in depositor pay-outs would limit moral hazard and should be a significant step towards debt mutualisation. However, whether this happens will depend on the political will of several member states. Amid the political controversies, we should remember that the most important issue is the outcome; whether it will address moral hazard and contribute to taxpayers’ safety. Some member states, which had plainly rejected the idea of debt mutualisation through so-called “Eurobonds”, fear that it could indirectly come back under the guise of deposit guarantee mutualisation through what we would coin “Eurobanks”.

National backstops that were used to recapitalize some European banks caused a sharp increase in sovereign indebtedness and helped create the vicious circle between over-indebted sovereigns and undercapitalized banks. Bail-in rules and a common bank-financed resolution fund were agreed to ensure that taxpayer funding of bank bailouts would be minimized in the future, however their use has been already questioned. Several measures, including bank recapitalization, resolution and deposit insurance mechanisms would have more credibility if there were a common fiscal backstop to be used as a last resort. This would increase trust in the whole system, even if the use of DGS is highly unlikely.

A staged approach to EDIS could therefore help to mitigate concerns about greater risk sharing, as should the European Commission’s moves to announce interlinked initiatives that make a full European deposit insurance scheme contingent on measures that would render bail-in more likely. The goals are to make deposits equally safe around Europe, reduce the exposure of banks to sovereigns, and reduce the link between banks and sovereigns.

Other measures to restore trust

Deposit insurance is not the only proposal for restoring trust as, more often than in the past, deposit runs have been replaced by market runs. However, the idea of a ‘No bail-out’ clause and the use of bail-in are currently being questioned and tested in Europe. And, as before, we could argue that bank bailouts are the consequence of a series of bad policy choices that will take more to correct than just creating the new institutional set up of the Banking Union. Therefore we need to remember to address decisively the underlying causes of the problem in order to increase the resilience of the sector. Measures for this include:

  • reforming the structure of too-big-to-fail banks,
  • introducing binding limits to leverage,
  • introducing binding limits to over reliance on short term liquidity through the Net Stable Funding Ratio (NSFR),
  • addressing the sovereign risk problem, and
  • creating a credible common fiscal backstop.

Without those, Banking Union will not deliver the depositor and taxpayer protection that policymakers seek. It could even make things worse by encouraging moral hazard and creating a false sense of security.


Source: https://www.finance-watch.org/blog/the-insufficient-role-of-edis-in-restoring-trust-in-banks/

Inline Feedbacks
View all comments
guest